American courts have never appeared to be very receptive to mathematical arguments,
in large part, some (including me) have assumed, because many judges do not feel
confident evaluating mathematical reasoning and, in the case of jury trials, no doubt
because they worry that unscrupulous, math-savvy lawyers could use formulas and
statistics to fool jury members. There certainly have been some egregious examples of
this, particularly when bogus probability arguments have been presented. Indeed, one
classic misuse of conditional probability is now known as the “prosecutor’s fallacy."
Another example where the courts have trouble with probability is in cases involving
DNA profiling, particularly Cold Hit cases, where a DNA profile match is the only hard
evidence against a suspect. I myself have been asked to provide expert testimony in
some such cases, and I wrote about the issue in this column in September and October
of 2006.
In both kinds of case, the courts have good reason to proceed with caution. The
prosecutor’s fallacy is an easy one to fall into, and with Cold Hit DNA identification there
is a real conflict between frequentist and Bayesian probability calculations. In neither
case, however, should the courts try to avoid the issue. When evidence is presented,
the court needs to have as accurate an assessment as possible as to its reliability or
veracity. That frequently has to be in the form of a probability estimate.
Now the courts are facing another mathematical conundrum. And this time, the case
has landed before the US Supreme Court. It is a case that reaches down to the very
foundation of our democratic system: How we conduct our elections. Not how we use
vote counts to determine winners, although that is also mathematically contentious, as I
wrote about in this column in November of 2000, just before the Bush v Gore Presidential
Election outcome ended up before the Supreme Court. Rather, the issue before the
Court this time is how states are divided up into electoral districts for state elections.
How a state carves up voters into state electoral districts can have a huge impact on the
outcome. In six states, Alaska, Arizona, California, Idaho, Montana, and Washington,
the apportioning is done by independent redistricting commissions. This is generally
regarded—at least by those who have studied the issue—as the least problematic
approach. In seven other states, Arkansas, Colorado, Hawaii, Missouri, New Jersey,
Ohio, and Pennsylvania, politician commissions draw state legislative district maps. In
the remaining 37 states, the state legislatures themselves are responsible for state
legislative redistricting. And that is where the current problem arises.
There is, of course, a powerful temptation for the party in power to redraw the electoral
district maps to favor their candidates in the next election. And indeed, in the states
where the legislatures draw the maps, both major political parties have engaged in that
practice. One of the first times this occurred was in 1812, when Massachusetts
governor Elbridge Gerry redrew district boundaries to help his party in an upcoming
senate election. A journalist at the Boston Gazette observed that one of the contrived districts in Gerry’s new map looked like a giant salamander, and gave such partisan redistricting a name, combining Gerry and mander to create the new word gerrymander.
Though Gerry lost his job over his sleight-of- hand, his redistricting did enable his party
to take over the state senate. And the name stuck.
Illegality of partisan gerrymandering is generally taken to stem from the 14th
Amendment, since it deprives the smaller party of the equal protection of the laws, but it
has also been argued to be, in addition, a 1st Amendment issue—namely an
apportionment that has the purpose and effect of burdening a group of voters’
representational rights.
In 1986, the Supreme Court issued a ruling that partisan gerrymandering, if extreme
enough, is unconstitutional, but it has yet to throw out a single redistricting map. In large
part, the Supreme Court’s inclination to stay out of the redistricting issue is based on a
recognition that both parties do it, and over time, any injustices cancel out, as least
numerically. Historically, this was, generally speaking, true. Attempts to gerrymander
have tended to favor both parties to roughly the same extent. But in 2012, things took a
dramatic turn with a re-districting process carried out in Wisconsin.
That year, the recently elected Republican state legislature released a re-districting map
generated using a sophisticated mathematical algorithm running on a powerful
computer. And that map was in an altogether new category. It effectively guaranteed
Republican majorities for the foreseeable future. The Democrat opposition cried foul, a
Federal District Court agreed with them, and a few months ago the case found its way
to the Supreme Court.
That the Republicans come across as the bad actors in this particular case is likely just
an accident of timing; they happened to come to power at the very time when political
parties were becoming aware of what could be done with sophisticated algorithms. If
history is any guide, either one of the two main parties would have tried to exploit the
latest technology sooner or later. In any event, with mathematics at the heart of the new
gerrymandering technique, the only way to counter it may be with the aid of equally
sophisticated math.
The most common technique used to gerrymander a district is called “packing and
cracking." In packing, you cram as many of the opposing party’s voters as possible into
a small number of “their” districts where they will win with many more votes than
necessary. In cracking, you spread opposing party’s voters across as many of “your”
districts as possible so there are not enough votes in any one of those districts to ever
win there.
A form of packing and cracking arises naturally when better-educated liberal-leaning
voters move into in cities and form a majority, leaving those in rural areas outnumbered
by less-educated, more conservative-leaning voters. (This is thought to be one of the
factors that has led to the increasing polarization in American politics.) Solving that
problem is, of course, a political one for society as a whole, though mathematics can be
of assistance by helping to provide good statistical data. Not so with partisan
gerrymandering, where mathematics has now created a problem that had not arisen
before, for which mathematics may of necessity be part of the solution.
When Republicans won control of Wisconsin in 2010, they used a sophisticated
computer algorithm to draw a redistricting map that on the surface appeared fair—no
salamander-shaped districts—but in fact was guaranteed to yield a Republican majority
even if voter preferences shifted significantly. Under the new map, in the 2012 election,
Republican candidates won 48 percent of the vote, but 60 of the state’s 99 legislative
seats. The Democrats’ 51 percent that year translated into only 39 seats. Two years
later, when the Republicans won the same share of the vote, they ended up with 63
seats—a 24-seat differential.
Recognizing what they saw as a misuse of mathematics to undermine the basic
principles of American democracy, a number of mathematicians around the country
were motivated to look for ways to rectify the situation. There are really two issues to be
addressed. One is to draw fair maps—a kind of “positive gerrymandering.” The other is
to provide reliable evidence to show that a particular map has been intentionally drawn
to favor one party over another, if such occurs, and moreover to do so in a way that the
courts can understand and accept. Neither issue is easy to solve, and without
mathematics, both are almost certainly impossible.
For the first issue, a 2016 Supreme Court ruling gave a hint about what kind of fairness
measure it might look kindly on: one that captures the notion of “partisan symmetry,”
where each party has an equal opportunity to convert its votes into seats. The
Wisconsin case now presents the Supreme Court with the second issue.
When, last year, a Federal District Court in Wisconsin threw out the new districting map,
they cited both the 1st and 14th Amendments. It was beyond doubt, the court held, that
the new maps were “designed to make it more difficult for Democrats, compared to
Republicans, to translate their votes into seats.” The court rejected the Republican
lawmakers’ claim that the discrepancy between vote share and legislative seats was
due simply to political geography. The Republicans had argued that Democratic voters
are concentrated in urban areas, so their votes have an impact on fewer races, while
Republicans are spread out across the state. But, while that is true, geography alone
does not explain why the Wisconsin maps are so skewed.
So, how do you tell if a district is gerrymandered? One way, that has been around for
some time, is to look at the geographical profile. The gerrymandering score, G, is
defined by:
G = gP/A, where
g: the district’s boundary length, minus natural boundaries (like coastlines and rivers)
P: the district’s total perimeter
A: the district’s area
The higher the score, the wilder is the apportionment as a geographic region, and
hence the more likely to have been gerrymandered.
That approach is sufficiently simple and sensible to be acceptable to both society and
the courts, but unfortunately does not achieve the desired aim of fairness. And, more to
the point in the Wisconsin case, use of sophisticated computer algorithms can draw
maps that have a low gerrymandering score and yet are wildly partisan.
The Wisconsin Republicans’ algorithm searched through thousands of possible maps
looking for one that would look reasonable according to existing criteria, but would
favor Republicans no matter what the election day voting profile might look like. As
such, it would be a statistical outlier. To find evidence to counter that kind of approach,
you have to look at the results the districting produces when different voting profiles are
fed into it.
One promising way to identify gerrymandering is with a simple mathematical formula
suggested in 2015, called the “efficiency gap." It was the use of this measure that
caused, at least in part, the Wisconsin map to be struck down by the court. It is a simple
idea—and as I noted, simplicity is an important criterion, if it is to stand a chance of
being accepted by society and the courts.
You can think of a single elector’s vote as being “wasted” if it is cast in a district where
their candidate loses or it is cast in a district where their candidate would have won
there anyway. The efficiency gap measures those “wasted” votes. For each district, you
total up the number of votes the winning candidate receives in excess of what it would
have taken to elect them in that district, and you total up the number of votes the losing
candidate receives. Those are the two parties’ “wasted votes” for that district.
You then calculate the difference between those “wasted-vote” totals for each of the two
parties, and divide the answer by the total number of votes in the state. This yields a
single percentage figure: the efficiency gap. If that works out to be greater than 7%,
the systems developers suggest, the districting is unfair.
By way of an example, let’s see what the efficiency gap will tell us about the last
Congressional election. In particular, consider Maryland’s 6 th Congressional district,
which was won by the Democrats. It requires 159K votes to win. In the last election,
there were 186K Democrat votes, so 186K – 159K = 26K Democrat votes were
“wasted,” and 133K Republican votes, all of which were “wasted.”
In Maryland as a whole, there were 510K Democrat votes “wasted” and 789K
Republican votes “wasted.” So, statewide, there was a net “waste” of 789K – 510K =
279K Republican votes.
There were 2,598M votes cast in total. So the efficiency gap is 279K/2598K = 10.7% in
favor of the Democrats.
I should note, however, that the gerrymandering problem is currently viewed as far more
of a concern in state elections than in congressional races. Last year, two social scientists published the results they obtained using computer simulations to measure
the extent of intentional gerrymandering in congressional district maps across most of
the 50 states. They found that on the national level, it mostly canceled out between the
parties. So banning only intentional gerrymandering would likely have little effect on the
partisan balance of the U.S. House of Representatives. The efficiency gap did,
however, play a significant role in the Wisconsin court’s decision.
Another approach, developed by a team at Duke University, takes aim at the main idea
behind the Wisconsin redistricting algorithm—searching through many thousands of
possible maps looking for ones that met various goals set by the creators, any one of
which would, of necessity, be a statistical outlier. To identify a map that has been
obtained in this way, you subject it to many thousands of random tweaks. If the map is
indeed an outlier, the vast majority of tweaks will yield a fairly unremarkable map. So,
you compare the actual map with all those thousands of seemingly almost identical, and
apparently reasonable, variations you have generated from it. If the actual map
produces significantly different election results from all the others, when presented with
a range of different statewide voting profiles, you can conclude that it is indeed an
“outlier” — a map that could only have been chosen to deliberately subvert the
democratic process.
And this is where we—and the Supreme Court—are now. We have a problem for our
democracy created using mathematics. Mathematicians looking for mathematical ways
to solve it, and there are already two candidate “partisan gerrymandering test” in the
arena. Historically, the Supreme Court has proven resistant to allowing math into the
courtroom. But this time, it looks like they may have no choice. At least as long as state
legislatures continue to draw the districting maps. Maybe the very threat of having to
deal with mathematical formulas and algorithms will persuade the Supreme Court to
recommend that Congress legislates to enforce all states to use independent
commissions to draw the districting maps. Legislation under pain of math. We will know
soon enough.
No comments:
Post a Comment
All comments are moderated. Anonymous postings will not be published. See our Commenting Policy.